

1 北京大学光华管理学院, 北京100871
2 中国农业大学经济管理学院, 北京 100083
3 Booth School of Business, The University of Chicago, Chicago IL 60637, United States
收稿日期:
2017-08-13出版日期:
2018-08-07发布日期:
2018-07-02Joint evaluation versus single evaluation: A field full of potentials
LU Xi1,2(

1 Guanghua School of Management, Peking University, Beijing 100871, China
2 College of Economics and Management, China Agricultural University, Beijing 100083, China
3 Booth School of Business, The University of Chicago, Chicago IL 60637, United States
Received:
2017-08-13Online:
2018-08-07Published:
2018-07-02摘要/Abstract
摘要: 人们有两种基本的评估模式:一是联合评估, 即所有选项一起呈现和被评估; 二是单独评估, 各个选项单独地呈现和被评估。所有决策都是在其中一种评估模式或者两种模式的中间地带中做出的。联合和单独评估可以导致偏好反转和次优选择, 理解其机制能帮助人们提高决策结果, 包括慈善、定价、消费、甚至幸福感等方面。作为对各类决策影响广泛的重要变量, 评估模式产生了不少反直觉的效应, 目前研究尚不全面, 是一块值得探索的沃土。
图/表 5

图1冰淇淋示意图(资料来源: Hsee, 1998)

表1JE/SE偏好反转的选项结构
选项 | 重要但难以单独 评估的属性 | 不太重要但容易 单独评估的属性 |
---|---|---|
选项A | 较好 (例:完成300次手术) | 较差 (例:毕业于爱荷华大学) |
选项B | 较差 (例:完成80次手术) | 较好 (例:毕业于哈佛大学) |
表1JE/SE偏好反转的选项结构
选项 | 重要但难以单独 评估的属性 | 不太重要但容易 单独评估的属性 |
---|---|---|
选项A | 较好 (例:完成300次手术) | 较差 (例:毕业于爱荷华大学) |
选项B | 较差 (例:完成80次手术) | 较好 (例:毕业于哈佛大学) |

图2可评估性和价值敏感性的影响因素


图3评估模式和效用函数(A)、时间折扣函数(B)、概率权重函数(C)(修改自: Hsee & Zhang, 2010)


图4室内温度和珠宝对幸福感的影响(资料来源: Hsee et al, 2009)

参考文献 40
[1] | Bazerman M. H., Gino F., Shu L. L., & Tsay C.-J . ( 2011). Joint evaluation as a real-world tool for managing emotional assessments of morality. Emotion Review,3( 3), 290-292. doi: 10.1177/1754073911402370URL |
[2] | Bazerman M. H., Loewenstein G. F., & White S. B . ( 1992). Reversals of preference in allocation decisions: Judging an alternative versus choosing among alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly,37( 2), 220-240. doi: 10.2307/2393222URL |
[3] | Chatterjee S., Heath T. B., & Min J. H . ( 2009). The susceptibility of mental accounting principles to evaluation mode effects. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making,22( 2), 120-137. doi: 10.1002/bdm.616URL |
[4] | Cooney G., Gilbert D. T., & Wilson T. D . ( 2016). When fairness matters less than we expect. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America,113( 40), 11168-11171. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1606574113URLpmid: 27638203 |
[5] | Desvousges W. H., Johnson F. R., Dunford R. W., Boyle K. J., Hudson S. P. , & Wilson, K. N.( 1992) . Measuring nonuse damages using contingent valuation: An experimental evaluation of accuracy Research Triangle Park, NC: RTI Press An experimental evaluation of accuracy. Research Triangle Park, NC : RTI Press. |
[6] | Dunn E. W., Wilson T. D., & Gilbert D. T . ( 2003). Location, Location, Location: The misprediction of satisfaction in housing lotteries. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin,29( 11), 1421-1432. doi: 10.1177/0146167203256867URL |
[7] | Evers E. R. K., Inbar Y., Blanken I., & Oosterwijk L. D . ( 2017). When do people prefer carrots to sticks? A robust “matching effect” in policy evaluation. Management Science,63( 12), 4261-4276. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.2016.2539URL |
[8] | Fox, C. R., &Tversky A , ( 1995). Ambiguity aversion and comparative ignorance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,110( 3), 585-603. doi: 10.2307/2946693URL |
[9] | Fredrick S., Loewenstein G., & O’Donoghue T . ( 2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature,40, 351-401. doi: 10.1257/002205102320161311URL |
[10] | Gilbert D.T., & Wilson, T. D . ( 2009). Why the brain talks to itself: Sources of error in emotional prediction. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences,364( 1521), 1335-1341. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2008.0305URLpmid: 19528015 |
[11] | Gino F., Moore D. N., & Bazerman M. H . ( 2008). No harm, no foul: The outcome bias in ethical judgments. Harvard Business School Working Paper, No. 08-080. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.1099464URL |
[12] | Gustafson C. R., Lybbert T. J., & Sumner D. A . ( 2016). Consumer knowledge affects valuation of product attributes: Experimental results for wine. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics,65, 85-94. doi: 10.1016/j.socec.2016.08.004URL |
[13] | Hsee C.K . ( 1993). When trend of monetary outcomes matters: Separate versus joint evaluation and judgment of feelings versus choice.Working paper. |
[14] | Hsee C.K . ( 1996). The evaluability hypothesis: An explanation for preference reversals between joint and separate evaluations of alternatives. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,67( 3), 247-257. doi: 10.1006/obhd.1996.0077URL |
[15] | Hsee C.K . ( 1998). Less is better: When low-value options are valued more highly than high-value options. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making,11( 2), 107-121. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1099-0771(199806)11:23.0.CO;2-YURL |
[16] | Hsee C.K., &Zhang J , (2004). Distinction bias: Misprediction and mischoice due to joint evaluation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,86( 5), 680-695. doi: 10.1037/0022-3514.86.5.680URLpmid: 15161394 |
[17] | Hsee, C. K., &Zhang J , ( 2010). General evaluability theory. Perspectives on Psychological Science,5( 4), 343-355. doi: 10.1177/1745691610374586URL |
[18] | Hsee C. K., Shen L. X., Zhang S., Chen J. Q., & Zhang L . ( 2012). Fate or fight: Exploring the hedonic costs of competition. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,119( 2), 177-186. doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2012.07.005URL |
[19] | Hsee C. K., Yang Y., Li N. H., & Shen L. X . ( 2009). Wealth, warmth, and well-being: Whether happiness is relative or absolute depends on whether it is about money, acquisition, or consumption. Journal of Marketing Research,46( 3), 396-409. doi: 10.1509/jmkr.46.3.396URL |
[20] | Hsee C. K., Zhang J., Lu Z. Y., & Xu F . ( 2013). Unit asking: A method to boost donations and beyond. Psychological Science,24( 9), 1801-1808. doi: 10.1177/0956797613482947URL |
[21] | Hsee C. K., Zhang J., Wang L. Y., & Zhang S . ( 2013). Magnitude, time, and risk differ similarly between joint and single evaluations. Journal of Consumer Research,40( 1), 172-184. doi: 10.1086/669484URL |
[22] | , , Kahneman D., &Deaton A , ( 2010). High income improves evaluation of life but not emotional well-being. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America,107( 38), 16489-16493. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1011492107URL |
[23] | Kahneman D., &Ritov I , (1994). Determinants of stated willingness to pay for public goods: A study in the headline method. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty,9( 1), 5-37. doi: 10.1007/BF01073401URL |
[24] | Kahneman D., &Tversky A , ( 1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica,47( 2), 263-292. doi: 10.2307/1914185URL |
[25] | Kahneman D., Wakker P. P., & Sarin R . ( 1997). Back to Bentham? Explorations of experienced utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,112( 2), 375-405. doi: 10.1162/003355397555235URL |
[26] | Kogut T, &Ritov I , ( 2005). The singularity effect of identified victims in separate and joint evaluations. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,97( 2), 106-116. doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.02.003URL |
[27] | Laibson D ( 1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,112( 2), 443-478. doi: 10.1162/003355397555253URL |
[28] | List J.A . ( 2002). Preference reversals of a different kind: The “more is less” phenomenon. American Economic Review,92( 5), 1636-1643. doi: 10.1257/000282802762024692URL |
[29] | Newman C. L., Howlett E., & Burton S . ( 2016). Effects of objective and evaluative front-of-package cues on food evaluation and choice: The moderating influence of comparative and noncomparative processing contexts. Journal of Consumer Research,42( 5), 749-766. doi: 10.1093/jcr/ucv050URL |
[30] | Okada E.M . ( 2005). Justification effects on consumer choice of hedonic and utilitarian goods. Journal of Marketing Research,42( 1), 43-53. doi: 10.1509/jmkr.42.1.43.56889URL |
[31] | Paharia N., Kassam K. S., Greene J. D., & Bazerman M. H . ( 2009). Dirty work, clean hands: The moral psychology of indirect agency. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,109( 2), 134-141. doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2009.03.002URL |
[32] | Powdthavee N., Riyanto Y. E., & Knetsc J. K . ( 2017). Economists’ judgments of publication lists with lower ranked journals included: Evidence from a survey experiment. Working paper. |
[33] | Shaffer, V. A., & Arkes, H. R . ( 2009). Preference reversals in evaluations of cash versus non-cash incentives. Journal of Economic Psychology,30( 6), 859-872. doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2009.08.001URL |
[34] | Shen L. X., Hsee C. K., Wu Q. S., & Tsai C. I . ( 2012). Overpredicting and underprofiting in pricing decisions: Evaluability in pricing decisions. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making,25( 5), 512-521. doi: 10.1002/bdm.746URL |
[35] | Sher S, & McKenzie, C. R. M . ( 2014). Options as information: Rational reversals of evaluation and preference. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General,143( 3), 1127-1143. doi: 10.1037/a0035128URLpmid: 24364684 |
[36] | Tu, Y. P., & Hsee, C. K . ( 2016). Consumer happiness derived from inherent preferences versus learned preferences. Current Opinion in Psychology,10, 83-88. doi: 10.1016/j.copsyc.2015.12.013URL |
[37] | von Neumann J., & Morgenstern O. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior (60th Anniversary Commemorative Edition) . Princeton: Princeton University Press. |
[38] | Yang A. X., Hsee C. K., Liu Y., & Zhang L . ( 2011). The supremacy of singular subjectivity: Improving decision quality by removing objective specifications and direct comparisons. Journal of Consumer Psychology,21( 4), 393-404. doi: 10.1016/j.jcps.2011.05.006URL |
[39] | Zhang J. ( 2015). Joint versus separate modes of evaluation. In G. Keren & G. Wu (Eds.), The wiley blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making (pp. 211-238). Portsmouth: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. |
[40] | Zikmund-Fisher B. J., Fagerlin A., & Ubel P. A . ( 2004). “Is 28% good or bad?” Evaluability and preference reversals in health care decisions. Medical Decision Making,24( 2), 142-148. doi: 10.1177/0272989X04263154URL |
相关文章 8
[1] | Gerd Gigerenzer, 栾胜华, 刘永芳. 人非理性且难教化?论支持自由家长主义的证据[J]. 心理学报, 2019, 51(4): 395-406. |
[2] | 刘隽,张震,孙彦,韩布新,陆勤,刘萍萍. 接受还是拒绝? 反应模式助推基础课与拓展课均衡选择[J]. 心理学报, 2019, 51(4): 437-449. |
[3] | 何贵兵, 李纾, 梁竹苑. 以小拨大:行为决策助推社会发展[J]. 心理学报, 2018, 50(8): 803-813. |
[4] | Nicolao Bonini, Constantinos Hadjichristidis, Michele Graffeo. 绿色助推[J]. 心理学报, 2018, 50(8): 814-826. |
[5] | 王晓庄, 安晓镜, 骆皓爽, 徐晟, 于馨, 胡施雅, 王玉涵. 锚定效应助推国民身心健康:两个现场实验[J]. 心理学报, 2018, 50(8): 848-857. |
[6] | 李爱梅, 王海侠, 孙海龙, 熊冠星, 杨韶丽. “长计远虑”的助推效应:怀孕与环境跨期决策[J]. 心理学报, 2018, 50(8): 858-867. |
[7] | 黄元娜, 宋星云, 邵洋, 李纾, 梁竹苑. 以小拨大:默认选项和反应模式效应助推中国器官捐献登记[J]. 心理学报, 2018, 50(8): 868-879. |
[8] | 张琴;汪涛;龚艳萍. 价格和品牌能否削弱来源国效应 —— 产品属性赋权对来源国效应的影响[J]. 心理学报, 2013, 45(12): 1381-1392. |
PDF全文下载地址:
http://journal.psych.ac.cn/xlxb/CN/article/downloadArticleFile.do?attachType=PDF&id=4239